Property cartel goes mainstream

Advertisement

Even writers at the New York Times are noticing that property developers won’t flood the market to bring down prices.

For years I’ve been trying to explain that the property market has a built-in speed limit on how fast it produces new housing.

Now others, like Conor Dougherty at the New York Times, are noticing. He wrote the following a few weeks back.

The United States has a deep, decades-old housing shortage. Also, at the moment, homebuilders across the country are pulling back on development because they can’t sell enough homes.

How can both of these things be true?

Advertisement

Despite dwelling prices still being near record highs, property developers have suddenly decided to stop producing.

That’s a puzzle if you subscribe to the idea that developers want to supply at a rate that is high enough to depress prices.

If you don’t subscribe to that idea, and instead have a good grasp of the theory of the market absorption rate because you’ve read my paper on it, then it is no puzzle at all.

Advertisement

In the absorption rate theory, price levels don’t determine supply. But the rate of growth in demand (how fast the demand curve for buying property shifts vertically) does. When demand falls, you stop supplying. Simple and predictable. After all, property owners are in the business of making money, not making housing cheap by flooding the market.

There are two comments I want to make about this article. First, I want to comment on how effective the property lobby has been in fostering the planning has caused a housing shortage story. Second, I note how economic theory is used as a weapon, not as a basis for understanding.

Advertisement

Thank you for reading Fresh Economic Thinking. This post is public so feel free to share it.

Share

The property lobby is good at their job

Advertisement
Advertisement

It was quite a surprise to see Randall Lewis, self-confessed landbanker and speculator, in that article talking about housing supply.

“This is going to have a significant impact on future supply,” said Randall Lewis, a principal at the family-owned Lewis Group of Companies, a developer of master planned communities in California and Nevada. Mr. Lewis’s company takes raw land and over the course of decades adds basic infrastructure like sewers, streets and traffic signals. When companies like his pull back, the number of lots homebuilders can use in the future declines.

“We are now saying we’re going to look project by project and say which ones are we are going to go ahead on and which we are going to take a pause on,” he said. “As a developer, the question is, how much money do you want to put in the dirt when you don’t know what the future is going to hold?”

(my emphasis)

Let’s not forget that Randall Lewis sponsors the UCLA Lewis Center to produce research that protects the value of his interests by blaming planning for its role in reducing the rate of new supply.

Advertisement

Yet here is is saying he can develop housing faster but won’t do it if it depresses prices.

Advertisement
The UCLA Lewis Center seems to have a problem
The Ralph & Goldy Lewis Center for Regional Policy Studies at UCLA is funded by a major property developer. While the group often lobbies for progressive causes, there appear to be financial interests working in the background, ensuring particular views are espoused, and people who hold those views are hired…

Read more

This quote also reminds me that one of the subtle ways the property lobby has manipulated the housing supply debate is by repeating the claim that builders choose how many homes to build. But builders can’t just build homes whenever they like. Only property owners can decide to subdivide. Only property owners can decide to build.

Advertisement

Builders are paid by property owners who choose how many new dwellings to build on their property.

Here’s an example of how the roles of building and developing get confused, by first saying that it’s all about builders adjusting to demand, then quietly noting the role of developers without ever being clear that they are the decision makers.

The slowdown in homebuilding wouldn’t have such a significant effect on the nation’s overall housing supply if builders could quickly adjust to demand, making up for the recessionary shortages during boom times. But they can’t: Housing is a hugely fragmented industry of mostly independent companies that includes developers that spend decades turning raw land into parcels that can be built upon and subcontractors that hire laborers by the hour. The system works fine when demand is strong, but deteriorates with even a modest sign of trouble and can take years to restart, creating a backlog that gets deeper each time building slows.

Advertisement

This quote is also strangely contradictory. It says that in a boom (demand is strong) there are many constraints, but also the system “works fine”. But when there is a bust (demand is weak) there are no constraints, but the system does not work fine.

A very strange argument.

The thing is, builders can quickly respond to demand for their construction services from property owners. There are a record number of homes under construction in the United States as of mid-2022, and the industry as a whole is able to increase dwelling construction by a factor of 4x over the business cycle.

Advertisement

If planning is constraining the rate of new housing development, how does it also allow the rate of supply to increase by 4x when property owners decide to build?

Where theory goes to die

Advertisement
Advertisement

What astounds me is that in Dougherty’s NYT article, Economics 101 apparently now says the opposite of what it said just two years ago.

Developers are responding the way Economics 101 says they should: by cutting prices on the houses they have already built, and by pulling the plug on virtually any project that wasn’t already too far along to be abandoned. Builders started construction on about 93,000 single-family homes in June, down 16 percent from a year earlier.

“Very smartly, builders are saying hey, let’s rein it in,” said Rick Palacios Jr., director of research for John Burns Real Estate Consulting. “Yes, we are undersupplied from a structural standpoint, but when rates roughly double in the space of three or four months, builders don’t care. They are planning their business for the now.” Some have puzzled over the idea that a price ceiling.

But just two years ago, the same NYT author was writing about how local politics was the main issue that determined the rate of new housing in the country. The Economics 101 argument I have been arguing against for years is that local NIMBYs restrict supply and this increases prices.

Advertisement

Perhaps it is property owners who choose the rate of new supply at all points in the business cycle? Sure, local politics might change where different types of new dwellings are built, but that doesn’t necessarily change the overall rate of new housing construction.

Read more

Advertisement
Advertisement

I have a bunch of papers about the housing market generally, and the rate of new housing supply, known as the absorption rate, specifically.

  1. A housing supply absorption rate equation (free versionpublished version)
  2. Time is money: How landbanking constrains housing supply (freepublished)
  3. The Australian housing supply myth (freepublished)
  4. We zoned for density and got higher house prices: Supply and price effects of upzoning over 20 years (free)
  5. When homes earn more than jobs: the rentierization of the Australian housing market (free and published)
Advertisement

Dr Cameron Murray is co-author of the Book Game of Mates. Subscribe to his written work at Fresheconomicthinking.substack.com.