Ray Dalio: Bring on MMT!

Via Ray Dalio of Bridgewater:

This article is for folks who are interested in economics, especially about how monetary and fiscal policy will work differently in the future. It will focus on Monetary Policy 3 (the new type that we will see more of around the world) and Modern Monetary Theory (a recently proposed new approach that has received a fair amount of attention). It comes in two parts. The first part is important for folks who care about such stuff but it’s a bit wonky and the second which shows historical cases is very wonky so feel free to wade into this in whatever depth suits your interest.

Part 1: Understanding MP3 and MMT

When I look at economies and markets I look at them in a mechanical way much like an engineer would look at cause-effect relationships of a machine. To me the economic machine has a limited number of basic cause-effect relationships (see “How the Economic Machine Works”) that can be put together in numerous ways that can lead to an infinite number of combinations, just like the 26 letters of the alphabet can be combined to make up an infinite number of words. More specifically there are two basic building blocks of economic policy, which are monetary and fiscal policy, and under these there are a few ways (taxing and spending for fiscal policy, and interest rates and quantitative easing and tightening for monetary policy) and under each of these there are various ways they can be configured. At the big picture level, monetary policy determines the total amount of money and credit (i.e., spending power) in the system, and fiscal policy determines the government’s influence on where it’s taken from (i.e., taxes) and where it goes (i.e., spending).

To me the most important engineering puzzle policy makers around the world have to solve for the years ahead is how to get the economic machine to produce economic well-being for most people when monetary policy does not work. I don’t mean that monetary policy won’t work at all; I mean that it won’t work hardly at all in stimulating economic prosperity in the ways that we are used to having it stimulate economic activity, which are through interest rate cuts (what I call Monetary Policy 1) and through quantitative easing (what I call Monetary Policy 2). That is because it won’t be effective in producing money and credit growth (i.e., spending power) and it won’t be effective in getting it in the hands of most people to increase their productivity and prosperity. Hence I believe we will have to go to Monetary Policy 3, which is fiscal and monetary policy coordination that is of a form that we haven’t seen before in our lifetimes but has existed in various forms in others’ lifetimes or faraway places. It is inevitable that this shift will happen because it is inevitable that central bankers will want to ease when interest rates are pinned at 0% and when quantitative easing will be ineffective in achieving the goal. I recently refreshed my prior exploration of past cases and future possibilities of such coordination, which I will share below.

Modern Monetary Theory is one of those infinite number of configurations that is in my opinion inevitable and shouldn’t be looked at in a precise way. For those of you who don’t know what Modern Monetary Theory is, it’s described here (link). It’s described differently by different folks so it has slightly different configurations. For example, some might change fiscal policy so that there is a wealth tax that is used to eliminate student loans, and others might change taxes and spending in other ways, and there are an infinite number of ways these changes can be configured that we shouldn’t delve into at this stage because that will drive us into the weeds and the particulars that will stand in the way of seeing the big important things. Also, people who are focusing on MMT as a package will limit their thinking to the specifics of that package rather than thinking about the wider range of MP3 policies to find the best one.

MMT’s most important configuration is the fixing of interest rates at 0% and there is the strict controlling of inflation via the changing of fiscal policy surpluses and deficits, which will produce debt that central banks will monetize. In other words, whereas during the times we have become used to, interest rates moved around flexibly and fiscal deficits (often) and surpluses (rarely) were very sticky so interest rates were more important in producing buying power and the cycles, in the future interest rates will be very sticky at 0% and fiscal policies will be much more fluid and important and the debts produced by the deficits will be monetized. In case you didn’t notice, that is by and large what has been happening and will increasingly need to happen. In other words, interest rates are now pinned near 0% in two of the three major reserve currencies (the euro and the yen) and there is a good chance that they will be pinned there in the third and most important reserve currency (the dollar) in the next economic downturn. As a result, fiscal policy deficits that are monetized is the contemporary stimulation configuration of choice. That existed long before there was a concept called “Modern Monetary Theory,” though MMT embraces it. Putting labels aside, it is certainly the case that the configuration of having 1) an interest rate fixed at around 0%, 2) more flexible fiscal policies with debt monetization to fund the resulting deficits with 3) rigorous inflation targeting exists and is increasingly likely, necessary, and possible in reserve currency countries. An added benefit of this approach is that the money and credit created can be better targeted to fund the desired uses than the process of having the central bank buy financial assets from those who have financial assets and use the money they get from the central bank to buy the financial assets they want to buy. There are many historical cases of this happening (see the 1930s-1940s prewar and war periods which, as you know, I think are analogous), which offer worthwhile lessons about how this was and could be engineered.

The big risk of this approach arises from the risks of putting the power to create and allocate money, credit, and spending in the hands of politically elected policy makers. In my opinion, for these MP3 policies to work well, the system would have to be engineered in a way that decision making would be in the hands of wise, not politically motivated, and highly skilled people. It’s difficult to imagine how the system will be built to achieve that. At the same time it is inevitable that we are headed in this direction.

Looking at Our Thinking about MP3 and MMT 

In the following section, I will outline some of my thoughts on what MP3 is likely to look like in more detail, but the main points me and my Bridgewater colleagues believe to be true are:

  • We agree with the notion that fiscal policy has to be connected with monetary policy to provide enough stimulus in the next economic downturn. That is because Monetary Policy 1 (based on moving interest rates) is in most cases either unable to happen alone or unable to happen much, and Monetary Policy 2 (based on central banks “printing money” and buying financial assets) has limited power to stimulate. For reasons explained in “Principles for Navigating Big Debt Crises,” as long as countries have their debts denominated in their own currencies, the combination of monetary and fiscal policies would likely work to smooth out economic downturns, and the only things that stand in the way are the limited capabilities of economic policy makers and/or the limited political abilities to do the right things.
  • We’ve described the coordination of fiscal and monetary policy as a type of Monetary Policy 3 (MP3)—and this is a critical policy tool when interest rate cuts (MP1) and QE (MP2) have limited effectiveness.
  • We think that interest rate cuts and QE will be significantly less effective in the next downturn for reasons we’ve described in depth elsewhere. We also don’t believe that monetary policy is producing adequate trickle-down. QE and interest rate cuts help the top earners more than the bottom (because they help drive up asset prices, helping those who already own a lot of assets). And those levers don’t target the money to the things that would be good investments like education, infrastructure, and R&D.
  • Obviously, normal fiscal policy is usually the way we handle those sorts of investments. But the problem with relying on fiscal policies in a downturn (besides them being highly politically charged) is that it is slow to respond: it has long lead times, you have to make programs, concerns over deficits can make it more challenging politically to pass fiscal stimulus, etc.
  • Imagine instead if you had taxes operating in a swing way, the same way that interest rates move, so that it could be a semi-automatic stabilizer. If you had a recession you would have the equivalent automatic reduction in taxes. On the opposite end, a tightening would result in a rise in taxes.
  • We could imagine semi-automatic increases in investments with high ROI to underfunded areas (e.g., education, infrastructure, R&D) rather than just going through financial markets to the areas that companies and investors find most profitable for them.
  • Funding such things with money printed by the central bank means that the government doesn’t have to worry about the classic problem of the larger deficits leading to more debt sales leading to higher interest rates because the central bank will fund the deficits with monetization (QE). As we’ve described several times before and have seen since the 2008 financial crisis, such monetization won’t cause too much inflation. That is because inflation is determined by the total amount of spending divided by the quantity of goods and services sold. If the printed money simply offsets some of the decline in credit and spending that happens in an economic downturn, then it won’t produce inflation, e.g., over the last decade central banks struggled with inflation being too low, not runaway inflation, while they have massively monetized debt.
  • The big question is who can be relied on to pull these levers well (central bank? federal government?). These tools have the power to do real good but they also can do real harm if not used responsibly. So the governance and decision rights would need to be carefully engineered. That’s a big topic I won’t get into here.
  • One specific policy that many MMT proponents have advocated for is a guaranteed jobs program. A lot depends on how that would actually be done. At a superficial level, I like the idea of people working to earn money through a government job in an economic downturn versus just getting welfare checks because staying employed is generally important for people’s psychology/emotional health as well as producing good outcomes (like keeping our cities clean and helping each other).
  • There are aspects of MMT that I disagree with. Here are just a couple:
  1. I disagree with the notion that businesses don’t make investments based on the cost of money and just make decisions based on business prospects. Both the cost of funds and business prospects are important. The cost of capital is a giant influence on the decisions of businesses to do things. For example, the low cost of capital was the reason US companies did huge amounts of share buybacks.
  2. Some MMTers blame inflation primarily on businesses’ excessive pricing power. While that might influence inflation, the bigger deal is that when you have a shortage of something (labor, commodities, etc.) and excessive demand for it, the price of that thing goes up.

What Monetary Policy 3 (MP3) Could Look Like

As I’ve noted, the policy tools that were sufficient to stimulate the economy in the last several cycles probably won’t be enough this time around. Monetary Policy 1—cutting interest rates—is limited by very low/negative rates across the developed world that probably can’t be lowered all that much more. Monetary Policy 2—quantitative easing—is limited by already very low longer-term interest rates/expected returns on assets and some central banks (especially the ECB) running low on bonds they can buy given current political constraints. Also, it is relatively ineffective in getting money and credit to those who don’t have financial assets, and it contributes to the widening opportunity gap. For these reasons, I believe in the next downturn developed countries will need to turn to “Monetary Policy 3” (MP3). In this study we will 1) define MP3, 2) give examples of it, and 3) focus on what was done in the 1930s.

Monetary Policy 3 comprises monetary policies that are more directed at spenders than at investors/savers (the groups that MP1 and MP2 principally target). In other words, they are policies that provide printed money to spenders with incentives for them to spend it. These sorts of policies will undoubtedly be politically controversial for both central banks and governments. The big question is whether these policies will hurt or help productivity. For reasons explained in the book Principles for Navigating Big Debt Crises, as long as countries have their debts denominated in their own currencies, these policies would likely work to smooth out economic downturns, and the only things that stand in the way are the limited capabilities of economic policy makers and/or the limited political abilities to do the right things, if the productivity produced is more than the amount of money and credit that is produced and spent. That’s why it’s important for policy makers to work through these political/other impediments and develop their “Plan B” now—what they’ll do when MP1 and MP2 don’t provide enough stimulus (e.g., buy equities, buy lesser quality debt, fund fiscal programs, etc.). Otherwise, working through those political considerations as the economy turns down might provide inadequate lead time, which can make the downturn much worse because there is nothing to offset the self-reinforcing downward pressures.

Below, I’ll share some of our prior research on what sort of forms these MP3 policies can take, updated with some recent examples.

Definition of Monetary Policy 3

Though most of us haven’t seen it in our lifetimes, it has existed in other lifetimes and other places. MP3 is a continuum of coordinated monetary and fiscal policies that vary who gets the money (private sector versus public sector) and how directly that printed money is provided (directly providing “helicopter money” to spenders versus more indirect means of financing spending). The following diagram maps many of the possible types of MP3 onto that continuum. In general, the more direct policies would be more effective, but also more politically difficult to do. And some of the least direct policies (or variants of them) have recently been used, but not at the scale that would likely be needed in the next significant downturn.

What MP3 Looks Like

No alt text provided for this image

We’ll walk through those policies in more detail (including some historical cases in which the policies were used), starting with MP3 policies that are targeted to the public sector:

  • The least direct option is an increase in debt-financed fiscal spending, paired with QE that buys most of the new issuance (e.g., Japan in the 1930s, the US during WWII, and nearly every large developed country following the 2008 financial crisis).
  • Central banks could lend to/capitalize development banks or other private/semi-private entities that would use the financing for stimulus-related projects (e.g., China in 2008).
  • Finally, there can be direct fiscal/monetary coordination, where the central bank explicitly aims to monetize government programs. This could occur via:
  • An increase in debt-financed fiscal spending, where the Treasury isn’t on the hook for the debt because:
  • The spending is paired with QE where the central bank retires the debt or commits to rolling the debt forever,
  • The central bank promises to print money to cover debt payments (e.g., Germany in the 1930s), or
  • Directly giving newly printed money to the government to spend, not bothering to go through issuing debt. Past cases have included printing fiat currency (e.g., Imperial China, the American Revolution, the US Civil War, Germany in the 1930s, the UK during WWI) or debasing hard currency (Ancient Rome, Imperial China, 16th century England).

These MP3 policies support spending in both the private and public sectors. What follows is a laundry list of examples. To be clear, we aren’t recommending any of these; we are just giving you tangible examples.

  • QE could be used to purchase real estate or other real goods, which would then ideally be used for socially beneficial ends. For instance, buying up abandoned properties in Detroit (which would support private landholders) and demolishing them to build parks.
  • Big debt write-down accompanied by big money creation (the “year of Jubilee”)
  • The less direct version of this is via explicitly targeting higher inflation or currency devaluation to lower the real value of the debt over time.
  • Central banks explicitly using currency intervention/depreciation as a lever would help with this. For instance, the dollar devaluation during the Great Depression (paired with a law invalidating gold-linked debt) effectively produced a big debt write-off.
  • In certain cases, governments directly created or negotiated debt write-downs (e.g., Ancient Rome, Great Depression, Iceland recently).

These MP3 policies are targeted toward the private sector:

  • MP3 policies could work through banks, providing them very strong incentives to lend. For instance, in addition to negative rates on excess reserves, the central bank could offer highly positive rates on required reserves—making it materially more profitable for banks to lend (versus building up excess reserves as central banks print money). Flavors of this program have recently been attempted in Europe, Japan, and the UK.
  • A different way of accomplishing this is incentivizing households to borrow through subsidized loans or guarantees. One example is the UK’s “Help to Buy” program, providing a five-year, interest-free loan for up to 20% of the property value to some home buyers.
  • So far, negative rates haven’t flowed through to households much. Central banks could experiment with explicitly aiming to disincentivize households from holding cash to induce households to spend. For instance, some people have suggested a “carrying tax” on holding cash, at the same rate as the negative interest rate (this was experimented with in Europe during the Great Depression). Other people have suggested invalidating physical money and using digital money only to make it easier to apply a negative interest rate to all cash holdings. Obviously this would be extreme.
  • Central banks could be given control over changing income tax rates or sales tax rates, perhaps within a band. They could then use it as an additional countercyclical lever to manage the economy, lowering taxes in recessions (pairing it with money printing) and raising taxes in good times.
  • Printing money and doing direct cash transfers to households (i.e., helicopter money). When we refer to helicopter money, we mean directing money into the hands of spenders of money to get them to spend (e.g., US veterans’ bonus during the Great Depression, Imperial China).
  • How that money is directed could take different forms—the basic variants are a) to either direct the same amounts to everyone or to aim for some degree of helping one or more groups over others (e.g., to the poorer more than to the rich), and b) to provide this money either as one-offs or over time (perhaps as a universal basic income). These variants could be paired with an incentive to spend it—like the money disappearing if not spent within a year.
  • The money could be directed to specific investment accounts (like retirement, education, or accounts earmarked for small business investments) to target it toward socially desirable spending/investment.
  • One potential way to craft the policy is to distribute returns/holdings from QE to households instead of to the government.
  • As a variant of helicopter money, central banks could give drawdown protection or guarantee a rate of return for stocks and riskier assets in order to further increase asset prices and support spending.

To reiterate, we aren’t offering any comments on the relative merits of these; we are just giving you a sense of the range and the number of historical cases that, if we were in the position of policy makers, we would be looking through. This examination process then has to consider what’s legal, and what’s politically acceptable, in each country. It’s a big job to work out what’s best, so that will take time. As a result, we believe that policy makers, especially central bankers, need to work hard on figuring this out now.

While we won’t offer opinions on each of these, we will offer our opinion that the most effective approach is fiscal/monetary coordination, because it assures that both the providing of money and the spending of it will occur. If central banks just give people money (helicopter money), that’s typically less adequate than giving them that money with incentives to spend the money. However, sometimes it is difficult for those who set monetary policy to coordinate with those who set fiscal policy, in which case other approaches are used.

As we look at these cases, keep in mind that sometimes the policies don’t fall exactly into these categories, as they have elements of more than one of them and they exist on the continuum mentioned above. There is not even a clear line of demarcation between MP2 (i.e., QE) and MP3. For example, if the government gives a tax break, that’s probably not helicopter money, but it depends on how it’s financed. There can be the government acting as the spender, with the central bank financing that spending without a loan—which is helicopter money through fiscal channels.

Part 2: Historical Cases

There are many historical cases of less effective MP1 and MP2 leading to cases of directing monetary policy to put I’d like to show you a bunch of historical cases on MP3 so you get a flavor of how they worked in the past without delving deeply into each because we would have to give you a big book of them to do that. The way I am going to do that is to first dig into Monetary Policy 3 during the Great Depression in the major economies at the time, and then superficially look at several other cases, including some QE cases that are beginning to cross the line to MP3 policies. What I will show you is long but interesting, and it includes how some things that we would consider implausible came about out of necessity. My hope is that in conveying such things we will all be able to open your thinking to a wider range of possibilities than you ordinarily might imagine. Because all of this material is rather long and wonky, I’ve posted it at www.economicprinciples.org for those of you who are interested. But since what happened in the global great depression is the most recent analogous case to today’s environment, I’m including that below if you’d like to examine just one iconic case.

Appendix: Detailed Historical Examples of Monetary Policy 3

We are now going to show you a large number of examples, some explained in more depth than others. They all exemplify the principles about MP3 that we just reviewed. If you find that there are too many, just skip the rest.

Example 1: In the US during the 1930s

As we’ve previously described, President Franklin D. Roosevelt’s policies—especially devaluing the dollar versus gold in 1933—helped create a “beautiful deleveraging.” But by 1935, policy makers were already expressing concern about how the US might offset the next economic downturn. In fact, that year the term “pushing on a string” was coined by a US representative questioning Fed Chair Marriner Eccles, who was concerned that the Fed could stop an expansion but couldn’t do much to offset a contraction. In this section, we describe how the US complemented MP1 and MP2 (low rates and an increase in money) with coordinated, creative fiscal policy—and relied on fiscal and monetary coordination to pull out of the 1937 downturn.

No alt text provided for this image

One of Roosevelt’s first major fiscal policy shifts was to engineer big debt write-downs as part of his “beautiful deleveraging” mix. He did that through a couple different policies. First, the US passed a law eliminating the “gold clause” from debt contracts.  Up until then, most long-term debts had gold indexation clauses that would have meant the devaluation would increase nominal debt burdens significantly. Eliminating that clause kept debt burdens the same even as the dollar fell, effectively creating a broad-based debt restructuring. Of course, that meant that the government legislated the breaking of contracts in a way that benefited debtors at the expense of creditors. This case was taken to the Supreme Court and decided 5-4 in the government’s favor.

Second, in 1933 Roosevelt created an agency to aid underwater mortgage borrowers, the Home Owners’ Loan Corporation (HOLC). This agency exchanged distressed mortgages for government-guaranteed bonds, purchasing the mortgages above foreclosure value, which encouraged lender participation. Then the HOLC would restructure the mortgages, lowering the interest rate and extending the term of the loan to 15 years (mortgages then typically had a 5- to 10-year maturity). In some cases (though not typically), the HOLC would also reduce the principal to keep the loan-to-value (LTV) ratio for borrowers below 80%. The agency purchased 1 million loans, about 20% of all mortgages, spending $4.75 billion (approximately 8% of GDP).

Roosevelt also created large government programs that directly employed people. The most significant was the Works Progress Administration (WPA), started in 1935. It lasted until the start of World War II and represented spending equal to approximately 2% of GDP annually. The WPA was focused specifically on employment, as it mandated that all projects spend at least 90% of costs on labor. Most projects were infrastructure-related, though there was also funding for white-collar and artistic work. The program hired librarians, musicians, writers, seamstresses, teachers, researchers, doctors, architects, and more. At its peak, it employed about 3.5 million people, over 6% of the labor force.

Further stimulus came in 1936, with a large early payment of a veterans’ bonus. This program is a particularly good example of a government borrowing in order to make direct cash transfers to households. What the governments literally did was to give the veterans non-marketable bonds, which could be exchanged for an immediate payment or held until maturity, paying an above-market discount rate. Also, veterans who had previously borrowed from the government against their future bonus payment received interest forgiveness. Eighty percent of the bonds were cashed in 1936, and the average recipient received approximately $500, more than the median individual annual income at that time. In total, the program represented a fiscal stimulus equal to approximately 2% of nominal GDP. The bonus recipients appeared to have a high tendency to spend the bonus and often used it to make down payments on purchases with credit, like residential investment and car purchases.

Throughout this period, the US rolled out a number of other programs that used fiscal incentives and macroprudential easings to stimulate credit and spending. These programs both supported existing borrowers and encouraged new lending for residential investment:

  • In 1932, Congress created the Federal Home Loan Bank System to act as a quasi-central bank and provide funding for S&L banks, and to set underwriting standards and collateral restrictions.
  • In 1933, the Home Owners Loan Act provided a federal guarantee to refinance mortgages on homes costing less than $20,000.
  • In 1934, the Federal Reserve was given the ability to set margin requirements (Regulation T) to purchase stocks. It began with “extremely lenient” margin requirements (according to a later Federal Reserve report) of 45%, at about the same level as a rule recently introduced by the New York Stock Exchange.
  • In 1934, Congress created the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) to insure home loans, which allowed easier underwriting standards (80% LTV and 20-year maturity) for insurance-eligible loans than what the private market was providing. One FHA program insured 20% of loans for improving residential properties, with up to a 5-year maturity.
  • In 1934, Roosevelt set up the Electric Home and Farm Authority to provide cheap loans for home electric appliances (under 10% interest rate, 5% down payment) for up to 36 months.
  • In 1935, Congress eased LTV and maturity restrictions for national banks (used to be only up to 5-year loans and 50% LTV, now 10-year and 60% LTV).
  • In 1937, the Federal Reserve lowered the equity margin requirement to 40% in response to the downturn (it had been increased in 1936).

Roosevelt’s fiscal spending programs were financed by a combination of spending cuts (Roosevelt cut back on the military early in his presidency) and deficit spending. This deficit spending wasn’t primarily financed by direct QE. The persistent gold inflows that followed the US’s devaluation increased the money supply: the banks, unwilling to increase lending to the private sector, significantly increased holdings of government debt to make a nearly guaranteed spread while funding government spending.

No alt text provided for this image

Government Response to 1937–38 Downturn

In 1937, the US entered a significant downturn—stocks declined more than 50%, growth turned negative, and the US slipped back into deflation. We won’t discuss the causes of this downturn, as we’ve described them before, but reductions in the WPA employment program and the fading effects of the veterans’ bonus in 1936 were significant contributors, along with devaluations in France and Italy causing dollar appreciation, sterilization of gold inflows, and increasing bank reserve requirements.

In 1938, the US eased monetary and fiscal policy in response to the downturn. In February of that year, Treasury Secretary Henry Morgenthau Jr. ended the gold sterilization program and began desterilizing the accumulated sterilized gold—moves akin to money printing. But policy makers discovered that their actions had very little effect—i.e., they were pushing on a string. From 1938 to 1940, increasing the money supply increased total bank reserves, but the new money was largely held as cash reserves, preventing it from flowing through to the real economy.

No alt text provided for this image

The government also passed a $2 billion fiscal stimulus bill, which included a significant increase in the WPA program (it had its biggest year in 1938). While these measures had some effect, the initial improvement in the economy was muted. Industrial production did not recover to peak levels until late 1939, inflation hovered around zero until late 1940, and equities remained approximately 30% below the level of early 1937.

The eventual pickup in economic activity in the US seems largely attributable to World War II. Prior to the US entering the war, production and government spending increased in order to supply the Allies and prepare for potential war. Meanwhile, gold inflows accelerated as investors sought a safe haven from the political situation of Europe and as the Allies began to purchase American supplies (prior to the enactment of Lend-Lease in March 1941).

No alt text provided for this image

Eventually, the common cause of World War II united the country and created a political consensus around policies of coordinated and extremely stimulative fiscal and monetary policy. The Federal Reserve summarized its “primary duty” in wartime as “the financing of military requirements and of production for war purposes.” Eccles, who was chair of the Fed through 1948, described his work as “a routine administrative job…The Federal Reserve merely executed Treasury decisions.” During World War II, government spending massively increased, and the money supply more than doubled. The Federal Reserve monetized government spending by maintaining a cap on long-term Treasury bond rates of 2.5% and short-term rates of 0.375%, and by stepping in to buy bonds when rates approached those levels.

Though the world was less globalized in the 1930s than it is now, the debt problems were then (like now) still global and interrelated. We could show you similar developments in a number of countries but, in the interest of brevity, will only touch on what happened in Japan and Germany. Similar things happened in many other countries.

Comments

  1. bcnichMEMBER

    Hnh can you summarise in 1 or 2 paragraphs, it’s too long to read and looks pretty boring
    I think everyone would appreciate

    I read that the Fed Reserve Act needs to be changed to do MMT and that won’t be easy ??

    • DominicMEMBER

      Allow me: the Magic Money Tree is a new term for an age old scheme. The govt, with the assistance of the central bank creates money out of thin air and distributes it to the people. We all get rich and live happily ever after.

      For evidence, look no further than the riches bestowed on Venezuela. Their stock market has been the best performing of any on the planet in the past 12 months: up 88,500%! (not a typo). Can’t say fairer than that now, can you?

      Bring it on.

      • Yes, it is all about the debt………..intellectual cover for printing the debt away. It is all good, they have promised only to put the tip in.

      • After all, the Zimbabwe solution is always politically easier than the Greece solution.

      • Did you actually read the article????
        It’s not about the 0.1%ers making money but rather as I read it it’s about the undeniable economic need for broad based consumption along with the Fiscal and Monetary mechanisms that are available to achieve this goal.
        To be honest I’m also stumped by the Zero bound problem associated with deploying excess “savings”. How do you stop all savings from simply being permanently parked in the fixed asset column. There’s zero capital productivity achieved when Capital is “invested” in existing over priced fixed assets and that’s a huge problem for any society that even dreams of Equitable outcomes for all, because Labour Productivity always
        rides on the shoulders of Capital Productivity.
        In Sydney everyone knows the insanity of $1M fibro shacks, but i need to live somewhere so I buy not forgetting that in a years time the bid will be $1.2M …(wow I’m rich I just made $200K) …It’s F’ed up, it’s profoundly inequitable, it has to change.
        This article explores alternatives because we’re going to need alternatives lest the bottom 25% rediscover that Pitch forks are extremely good tools for implementing wealth redistribution…but that doesn’t really benefit anyone.

      • DominicMEMBER

        @HnH
        I deplore war and prefer instead a strong economy to A) build prosperity and B) draw people out of poverty.

        Sadly, we live in a guns ‘n butter world. A policy guaranteed to drag us all into the abyss (eventually).

      • DominicMEMBER

        @fisho
        No I did not read the article. It really would be a waste of my time. MMT ‘done right’ is still ‘printing prosperity’ i.e. intellectually bankrupt as a concept. I really don’t have time for these bigwigs and ‘intellectuals’ who think you can sustainably pull ‘money’ out of your ar$e and pay for real goods and services with it. When you reach that point, money really has no value and huge inflation must inevitably ensue. The currency that Govt creates is actually worthless and little more than a confidence trick — it works while people believe in it. One day they’ll have good reason not to.

        And before anyone holds Japan up as a shining example of MMT ‘working’, save your breath. They are on borrowed time – especially once the rest of the large economies are no longer there to prop them up. Their trade surpluses have always been a prop along with strong capital inflows and they have been a reserve currency for quite some time. Once those props disappear, they’re in awful trouble — the inflation they’ve been wanting for 30yrs will arrive in spades and then they’ll really have a problem.

      • Dominic contributing 0 to the conversation, with his 0 understanding, as usual

        Please stop engaging him

      • Agree with Dominic’s 2nd reply to his own comment.
        Well said, showing good knowledge of the real, unfortunate future.

    • bcnich, if the Fed directly finances treasury, you will get rampant inflation.
      The Federal Reserve Act will have to be changed, but it will be very hard for this to happen, but it is possible.
      Most intelligent people don’t want MMT, but if times get desperate, who knows.
      Once/if US rates go back to zero and stay at O, then who knows what might happen.
      Would you prefer rampant inflation or Japanese deflation?

      • The 1% are no fools and MMT will not deflate their asset. All they will need to do is use their superior creditworthiness to leverage deeper and outbid the locals to get their hands on real assets, and pay back the debt with the devalued currency later.

      • DominicMEMBER

        And there I was thinking that inflation raised the price of assets, not deflated them.

        Fack me, I think the world has been turned on its head. Up is down, black is white, day is night.

        MMT is quackery. End of. Numerous very smart people have crushed MMT and the list grows, but no, the intellectuals responsible for f*cking our economy up (central bankers, academics etc) are now proposing their next great scheme to fix the issues created by their past failures. You couldn’t make this up.

      • You’re a cretin, dominic

        The implication is that rising wages reduce the power and profit share of Capital, and redistribute it to labour

        Can you please stop sh!tting up this thread now?

      • DominicMEMBER

        @Coming
        Yes, once the clever people have worked their magic with monetary policy all will be well in the world and the fairies and unicorns will come out and celebrate. Time for your milk and cookies, yet?

      • Actually, raising the minimum wage will induce inflation and inflate the outstanding debt away, without changing the privileged control of the printing press. This “solution” is not new, though – after all, Straya has been doing it all the time. Only this time the outstanding debt is so large that a massive raise would be required, perhaps to the neighborhood of $200 per hour.

        But rising wages will not reduce the power and profit share of Capital, and redistribute it to labour.

      • DominicMEMBER

        The bottom line is: policy cannot compel the economy. You cannot repeal the laws of economics any more than you can shout at the wind to stop. If you raise wages then you raise prices — even a lobotomised chimp can see that. You end up with a cat chasing its tail scenario. And you cannot tax your way to prosperity any more than you can print your way to prosperity. Printing just re-distributes wealth — it does not create it.

        All these ‘clever’ solutions doing the rounds get us absolutely nowhere — this is all about people who think they’re smart trying convince others they’ve discovered the secret to alchemy. The best thing that could ever happen to the economy is for Govt to butt out entirely, down-size significantly and let the free market do its work. There are no magic solutions here. Period.

      • “If you raise wages then you raise prices — even a lobotomised chimp can see that.”

        Yes, the end result will be broad-based inflation but it is still worth looking at its machinery. Doing so will help one see why raising the minimum wage will not “help” those who are actually doing the minimum wage jobs but help the debtors.

        If the minimum wage were raised to, say, $200 per hour, all the other wages would rise more or less proportionally. Why? The second minimum wage would command a higher rate for more demanding jobs than the minimum wage jobs. So the effect would cascade through the whole wage structure overnight. Then the costs of the goods and services will rise accordingly. Why? First, the costs of the products made by the minimum wage jobs must rise to cover the higher costs, and so do the costs of other goods. Then, farmers, for example, who were not directly affected by the initial increase of the wage structure, would soon find it impossible to make their ends meet without raising the prices of their products. The same will happen to the other small businesses which might not have been directly affected at first.

      • drsmithyMEMBER

        If you raise wages then you raise prices — even a lobotomised chimp can see that.

        It never ceases to amaze me how you will adamantly insist things that have actually happened, are impossible.

  2. mikef179MEMBER

    So basically what he is saying is that all that stuff in the 1930’s didn’t really help much and it was really the war that pulled the US out of the Great Depression.

    So I guess we need a world war to fix everything?

    How about we just acknowledge that compounding interest doesn’t work, as debt can’t just keep exponentially increasing?
    Trying to inflate it away can’t keep up unless you go to hyperinflationary territory, at which point you are destroying savers among other things. Maybe the muslims have it right when it comes to interest.

  3. a guaranteed jobs program

    like keeping our cities clean

    I knew it!

    The gutters are cleaned by trucks now, there is a cash for cans scheme, and some voters are too injured to work!

    because staying employed is generally important for people’s psychology/emotional health

    Ah yes. Working for a psychopathic boss is good for our health.

    I’m fifty one years old and I’ve only ever had one job that increased my feelings of self worth.

    I have had to quit multiple jobs because I felt worthless and like I would be better off dead.

    they are conflating “socialising” with working – the reason unemployed people are not socialising is because they cannot afford to

    • Yes, let’s not provide any incentive for people to contribute to the function/beauty/security/productivity etc of the world

      Let’s just give them free stuff so they can sh!tpost on internet website all day

      The retard brigade is out in full force in this thread

      • I’m not usually one to agree with Jacob yet the job guarantee concerns me. When looking at how the current employment assistance and replacement systems are run I do worry about the treatment on those employed under a job guarantee and the type of work they would be put to. While I see the argument that there is dignity in work there are also many jobs that and places of employment that are demeaning. Having looked into both the JG and UBI I prefer the UBI. The studies done into its older implementations, and results from recent smaller scale trials show that there’s a net saving due to increased mental and physical health and better educational and broader social outcomes. (As always, the manner of implementation and level of other public services will greatly effect its level of benefit.) One option, that I don’t often hear put forward is a UBI and JG combination. If a UBI were to be out in place and there was still a big gap in the employment market then the JG could be there as that mid point. The UBI would hopefully minimise the chance of a JG being poorly run as people could walk away without being left high and dry.

        The above is an aside to the validity of MMT itself.

      • UBI is ultimately a form of welfare for the rich as well as the poor

        The handouts will eventually end up as privatised profits

        The rich would be especially loathe to have a GJG, because it creates the possibility of government-funded and run services and infrastructure (NBN, electricity, roads, schools, hospitals etc)

        This minimises the opportunity of private enterprise to carve out profits and to create oligopolies

      • Coming,

        I don’t disagree that it is a possibility that the UBI could be implemented in that or another poor manner. The little I’ve read into proposal of the proponent who would like to be American President, Andrew Yang, worries me. I don’t question his desire to reduce poverty and help people. I do question his broader political economic look which believes that silicon valley style entrepreneurialism is the answer. He is also proposing an American GST to help fund it, which would be a regressive tax used to fund it.

        Maybe because the JG is a bit newer than the UBI, or because generally people are more comfortable with that idea, I don’t see it being scrutinized as heavily. What is to say that the same overall political economic structure isn’t changed and that the JG just ends up being used to create cheap labour for corporations? That’s what’s happening in prisons in America. The oversight of the JG could also be corpratized. That would lots of ticket clipping and rorting while removing oversight. Sarina Russo overseeing the JG would not inspire confidence.

        My point is that anyone that argues against a UBI on the basis of a poor implementation should not them assume that the JG will be well implemented. Start with ideal implementations of both and work backwards. Both should take into account any recent examples and the general of the society that they will be introduced into. One the good, and completely obvious once I thought about it, insights I got from Ha-Joon Chang was that successful political economies are not transportable due to many different reasons. These include natural advantage, development history, education levels, future direction, etc, etc. So perhaps a UBI could work in Japan and a JG in Canada. Or vice-versa. Or a combination of both.

  4. Incredible. MB leads the charge in calling out the damage done by uncapped money creation by the private sector. And for which MB deserves accolades.

    Yet somehow MB thinks giving our corrupt politicians (whose failures MB documents) access to money creation will turn out well. It is naïve in the extreme.

    If you advocate for infrastructure building stimulus, you can achieve that with a deficit or infrastructure bonds without giving the government the power to create money. Once you do that good luck taking it way. And just watch the greens and reds pile on the pressure to use it for non-infrastructure spending.

    • You are fulfilling your destiny, Stephen. Emperor will show you the true nature of the Force. He is your master now.

    • You understand, Stephen, that advocating for “deficit” or “infrastructure” bonds is basically welfare for the rich?

      The people who buy the bonds will then receive risk-free income for doing nothing other than having already accumulated capital

      It really boggles the mind that the people in this thread are so stupid, but I’m sure that you and Dominic are not paid shills operating for the Davos elite and bond funds

      If you think giving money creation powers to politicians is bad, and you think giving it to banks is bad, then who should have the money creation powers?
      Or should we just stick with the exact number of dollars we have right at this moment? And watch human productivity grind to a complete halt as people hang on to the rapidly appreciating and increasingly scarce dollars rather than using them?

      Cretin

      • The point was MB advocates for infrastructure-based fiscal stimulus. If it is going to happen, better to fund it through a deficit than to print money. Anyway it doesn’t matter how you fund it, it won’t change who builds and operates it. And it won’t stop them taking their private tax.

        Me personally. I’d rather us take our medicine straight and get on with life after a proper shakeout. I don’t have any faith in the powers that be to fix this mess, I’d rather get out of this mad experiment. We have brought forward demand and we are now in a hole, bringing forward even more demand isn’t going to fix the cause of our troubles.

        You have jumped to some extreme conclusions. Especially on money creation and deficit funding.

      • Why is it advantageous to fund it through bond sales?
        Why do governments need to sell debt?

        Why do you want to give free income/handouts to owners of capital?

      • I don’t think it is advantageous to fund the infrastructure-based fiscal stimulus through bond sales or governments “need” to sell debt. I don’t think it will make much difference (in terms of the power and profit share of capital vs labor) whether governments fund it through bond sales or through helicopters. Why not?

        Once upon a time there was an indebted publicly traded company, Straya Inc. There were two types of shareholders, the rich (who are largely creditors) and the indebted poor. Straya Inc, being indebted itself, one day decided it was time for yet another round of pro-rata capital raising.

        Concerns were raised that the poor would not be able to afford to subscribe in full and as a result the ownership of Sraya Inc would further shift to the rich after the capital raising. Then some clever folk came forward and proposed to deploy helicopters. Everyone agreed that it would be a brilliant idea and so the helicopters flew off.

        Strangely, the poor, although no longer indebted (at least for now), ended up owning an even smaller share of Straya Inc after the dust settled. So what happened?

        The poor, after having received the helicopter money, rightly paid off their outstanding debt and used a small portion of the helicopter money to undersubscribe for the pro-rata capital raising.

        The rich, not only deployed the full amount of the helicopter money and their savings but also directed the proceeds from the debt repayment by the poor to oversubscribe for the pro-rata capital raising.

  5. What distinguishes MMT from… was it ?Jackson? who wanted the govt to issue money directly in the US?

    And didn’t Swanny/Rudd *practically* pull a top right direct to consumer MMT during the Go hard, Go households $900 stimulus?

  6. – MMT is based on the myth that “money printing” will help the economy. The MMT folks overlook that the (commercial) banks have been “printing money” for many decades and yet countries like Argentina went bankrupt.

  7. Stop crying and just put up the interest rates to a more long term nominal level and let defaults occur.
    Interest, credit and debt is what keeps the cycles going and needs to reset at some point. I have never seen so much whining about a reset that they want to flip the board game over and change the rules.

  8. If you read the article you’ll discover that Ray Dailo is really talking about the process by which we make the very transition that you (Domanic) are saying is absolutely necessary.
    Is there a good way to do this? we all know that war is natures (and probably humanities) best tool for resolving these sorts curly questions but maybe there are alternatives …that’s what he is exploring.
    How would it work?
    How do we maintain Labour Productivity and it’s close cousin Consumption (no demand = reduced supply = reduced productivity for a fixed labour force)
    Consumption is necessary
    Capital Productivity is necessary
    Labour Productivity is necessary

    These are the core elements of Capitalism so unless we want to re-examine the failures of Planned Economies (aka Socialism or War) we’re kinda stuck with working with the Model we have and tweaking it in such a manner as to keep the cogs turning.

    • Why are we transitioning exactly? I also don’t understand how war or socialism are symptoms of the current model. War happens in the current model but one would be naive to think its the failures of the current model. I will go one further and say war would also happen under MMT.

      I also find it strange to use wars during MP1 and MP2 as example of how MMT has worked. However this MP3 policy worked under the umbrella of MP1 and 2 during these times and so to assume that MP3 could work alone in its entirety is foolish. In fact one could say that MP1 and 2 allows for MP3 to work when needed and removed when not.

  9. Moments like these you need a Minsky

    “Why are we transitioning exactly?”

    “one would be naive to think its the failures of the current model”.

    An answer….from the same author;

    “Capitalism is no longer working for most Americans, according to one hedge-fund billionaire, who says the expanding wealth gap dividing the haves and have-nots is creating a volatile environment with disturbing parallels to the economic and social upheaval of the 1930s”.
    The wealth gap is at its widest point since the late 1930s, with the top 1% owning more than the bottom 90% combined, “which,” Dalio notes, “is the same sort of wealth gap that existed during the 1935-40 period (a period that brought in an era of great internal and external conflicts for most countries).”
    “Who’s to blame for this predicament? Dalio says it’s not “evil rich people” or “lazy poor people” — it’s capitalism itself”.

    https://www.marketwatch.com/story/founder-of-worlds-biggest-hedge-fund-says-capitalism-needs-urgent-reform-2019-04-05